Monetary mix-up


Indian Express, 2 April 2007


Many people are bewildered, wondering what is hurting them more -- inflation or interest rate hikes which are meant to address the problem of inflation. While inflation may be high at 6-7 percent, it does not yet appear to be runaway and completely out of control. In contrast, monetary policy, with call money rates going above 70 percent, appears to be a policy that has lost control. Neither is the policy able to provide stable conditions in financial markets, nor is it able to control inflation.

Why has this situation arisen? Money gets created in two ways. First, when RBI buys a dollar with rupees, it creates rupees. Second, when RBI lends to the government, it creates rupees. For many years now rupees have been added to the existing stock of money circulating in the economy mainly through dollar purchases of RBI. Indeed, dollar purchases have put so much money into the economy that the RBI has sold government bonds to banks to suck out rupees from the system. When banks buy government bonds from the RBI, the rupees that entered the economy through RBI intervention in the foreign exchange market, leave the system. The impact of the forex intervention is thus 'sterlised'. Sterlilised intervention is sometimes used by central banks to stabilise conditions in the market. It rarely works as a long term sustainable policy.

Today sterilised intervention is hitting its limits. If the RBI had been able to fully sterilise its foreign exchange market operations, it would have been able to reduce the high growth of credit in the economy gently over the last few years. In the last three years bank credit has been growing at 30 percent. The RBI talks of a 20 percent growth in credit as one that would sustain demand at a level at which inflation would remain between 5 to 5.5 percent. The policy has not worked because banks have been reducing their holding of government bonds and giving out loans instead. Since the economy has been booming there has been enough demand for loans. With low appetite for government bonds, the rate of money and credit growth coming from RBI's rupee manipulation exceeds the contraction through sterilisation.

But if money growth has been so much faster than what was desirable, why did the RBI not slow down on intervention? Slowing down on the forex intervention would have meant that the rupee would have appreciated. An appreciation in the rupee can slow down India's exports and one argument for the continued intervention was that India needs to promote exports. This argument overlooks the fact that export competitiveness is not determined by the nominal exchange rate, but by the real exchange rate, which also takes into account the differences in the rates of inflation of other countries. If our trading partners or competitors have low inflation, their costs of production remain low. We lose export competetiveness when our inflation rate is higher than theirs. So what we are gaining by keeping the rupee from getting stronger, we are losing through inflation. This would not have happened if we had successfully sterilised our forex operations and not got higher inflation. But while China may be able to force banks to holds higher levels of governemnt securities to sterilise central bank operations, in India even public sector banks have been offloading government bonds and increasing their loan portfolios, resulting in RBI's loss of control over growth in money supply.

When hitting against constraints to sterilised intervention, two things are possible: either the central bank gives up on forex intervention, or it tries 'indirect sterilisation'. The latter refers to use of interest rate policy to reduce domestic demand. This is what has been happening in India for more than a year. The RBI has continuted its intervention, done direct sterilisation, found it inadequate, and has gone in for indirect sterilisation. But indirect sterilisation has a very interesting property. Higher domestic interest rates attract more capital from abroad as returns in India are higher. If the central bank continues with its currency manipulation, it faces even greater pressure on the rupee and ends up in intervening even more. This means the need to do sterilisation rises and interest rates have to be pushed up further, which of course further attract capital. The vicious cycle only gets worse and worse until the central bank admits that it has lost control and gives up on intervention.

Actually the RBI has done even worse than the standard indirect sterilisation methods. It has applied the axe on credit by using the CRR (Cash Reserve Ratio). This disrupts business activity all over the economy. Even when people are willing to pay more, they are unable to get credit.

In the olden days one way out would be to block foreign capital. Even today, the first response of a central bank that is used to a control raj for many decades might be to think that greater capital controls should be brought back and this would solve the problem. The difficulty with this approach is that the country's political economy will not allow this to happen. Industry is happy to borrow cheap abroad. It will not sit quietly and accept a policy reversal on openness. Second, the trade account offers a channel through which money will flow in and out of the country. Yes, honest resident Indians will suffer, but the rich and powerful will find ways to move money, as they always have.

What needs to be done next? The only way out of this mess to get a change in the framework of monetary policy away from the focus on the rupee. Allowing the rupee to appreciate will help reduce inflation and put a stop to the need to raise interest rates. There may be a period of turmoil in forex markets, but it is better than putting millions of households and firms out of business by hiking interest rates and choking off credit.


Back up to Ila Patnaik's media page
Back up to Ila Patnaik's home page